The continuing crisis in Latin America
s third largest economy is a matter of global concern. At a Stern event, Argentina
s former Economic Minister and a former governor of its Central Bank dissect the roots of the nation
s problems and point toward solutions.
|
he collapse
of the Argentinian economy has been one of the most hotly debated economic events of the past year. Fiscal and
monetary reforms enacted in the late 1980s seemed to tame the country
s cycle of hyperinflation and devaluation. In 1991, Argentina established a currency board, under which the value
of the peso was pegged directly to that of the U.S. dollar. After several years of growth in the mid-1990s, the
Argentine economy began to slip into recession. And as government deficits rose and the solvency of the banking
system came into question, depositors began to withdraw their funds. Amid social unrest, Argentina announced in
late 2001 that it would stop paying interest on its $155 billion in foreign debt the largest such default in
history. In January 2002, it abandoned the currency board and let the peso float against the dollar. Within a month,
the peso had lost half its value, destroying savings and rendering borrowers unable to repay debts.
At NYU Stern on November 26, 2002, a distinguished panel gathered to discuss the Argentinian
crisis and its implications. It included: Domingo F. Cavallo, the Henry Kaufman Visiting Professor at NYU Stern,
who served as Minister of Finance for Argentina from 1989 to 1996 and was the architect of the currency board;
Mario Blejer, a former governor of the Central Bank of Argentina and currently Director, Bank of England Centre
for Central Banking Studies; and Nouriel Roubini, associate professor of economics at NYU Stern, and a former senior
economist for international affairs at the White House Council of Economic Advisers. NYU Stern Economics Professor
Paul Wachtel moderated the discussion.
PAUL WACHTEL: Should Argentina have left the currency board?
DOMINGO CAVALLO: When a domestic currency has to compete with foreign
currencies you have to create some credibility so you need a tutor. Most modern currencies had gold as a tutor
during the gold standard period. More recently, it
s been the dollar. And we thought that using a tutor for a while would be important. The time to exit the currency
board and abandon the tutor is when your currency has become credible. Argentina could have exited the currency
board in 1997 after having averted the devaluation forecasted at the time. The currency was growing very fast and
there was a significant inflow of capital. If the Central Bank had let the peso float, it would have appreciated
vis-a-vis the dollar. That
s what happened with Singapore in the 1970s, and they started to have a strong currency.
But Argentina didn
t abandon the currency board for a very simple reason. As part of the competition for the presidency in 1999, the
government was trying to finance very large deficits of the provincial governments. [Then-President] Carlos Menem
would call the private banks and get them to provide financing to the provinces. This fiscal management, which
stemmed from the political competition, prevented the government from taking the natural opportunity to exit the
currency board.
WACHTEL: Let me ask Mario about that, and more generally, whether emerging
economies should maintain currency boards?
MARIO BLEJER: I
d distinguish between the currency crisis and the crisis in confidence. Governments were clearly afraid of abandoning
the one-to-one peso to dollar peg. In 1997, the main constraint was the cost. They didn
t want to have the risk of having the currency first appreciate and then depreciate. The IMF put out a paper that
concluded you should exit currency boards when things are good. This is appealing academically, but it
s not practical advice. It
s like saying you should have a divorce when the marriage is going well.
The crisis really stems from the inconsistency between fiscal policies and the saving investment
balances. The sharp increase in the government
s fiscal deficit brought a very high increase in the interest rate spreads. The convertibility of the peso to the
dollar helped bring down hyper-inflation in Argentina, but this rigidity imposed certain constraints on the conduct
of macro-economic policy that were not respected.
NOURIEL ROUBINI: I'd like to put Argentina in the context of other emerging
market crises we
ve seen in the last decade in Mexico, Thailand, Korea, Malaysia, Indonesia, Russia, Brazil, and most recently in
Turkey. One of the lessons we've learned from all these episodes is that capital markets tend to collapse. And
when this happens, emerging markets tend to move either toward flexible exchange rates or toward hard pegs. Until
recently I think people categorized dollarization and currency boards as among the hard pegs. But after what happened
in Turkey and Argentina, we realize that if your policies are not consistent, even a currency board can collapse.
"The convertibility of the peso to the dollar helped bring down hyper-inflation in
Argentina, but this rigidity imposed certain constraints on the conduction of macro-economic policy that were not
respected."
|
In each crisis, fixed exchange regimes collapsed and there was some overvaluation of the
currency. That led to current account deficits, which led to an accumulation of foreign debt or foreign liabilities.
When you have a current account deficit, you can finance it either by equity inflows, or in the form of debt. These
countries all had too much debt and too little equity. And eventually that means the banks are going to be in trouble.
Argentina met most of these conditions. Two thirds of Argentinian bank assets were in debt to households or to
the government, which was borderline insolvent.
How can countries be less vulnerable to financial crisis? First of all, you need sound
macroeconomic and fiscal policy. And if you're an emerging market, you have to overachieve. Countries like this
should have debt ratios that are lower than those of developed countries. Having a sustainable exchange regime
means either you pay the cost of dollarization and few countries are truly willing to do so or otherwise go
to a floating regime and maybe use inflation targeting or some other anchor as a way to stabilize inflation. You
can use regulation to reduce the currency mismatch by encouraging more equity investment. And if you have periods
in which hot money is flowing in, some controls on inflows of capital may be useful.
WACHTEL: So, Domingo views the dollar as a tutor, Mario views the dollar
as not being responsible, and Nouriel views the dollar as being a monster that helped create the crisis. Perhaps
we can turn our attention back to the present situation in Argentina, and ask what are the prospects for policy
and economic reform in Argentina?
BLEJER: To restore and start rebuilding confidence you need to pacify
some sectors, like the foreign exchange market. I'm not talking about the need to fix the exchange rate, but the
need to stop chaos. Certain types of capital control may restore that sort of confidence. The situation in January
2002 was very chaotic in Argentina: a lack of confidence in the peso, the abolition of convertibility, and a lack
of confidence in the government.
The supposed outcome at that point would have been hyper-inflation, and the total collapse
of the financial sector. We
ve avoided that so far. You have to intervene in the foreign exchange markets, provide liquidity to the banking
sector, and have a very active and aggressive monetary policy with very high interest rates.
These are the preconditions for a turnaround. The question is if the turnaround can be
sustained. The problems are daunting, because the foreign and domestic debt has not been negotiated, wages are
frozen, and inflation is 40 percent.
CAVALLO: For economic growth, you need strong institutions. And for that,
you need a well-functioning political system. The historical problem was that Argentinians in general did not consider
paying debts as something that you had to do. In a sense inflation was a reflection of that attitude. The government
would print money to finance its deficit, and would permanently devalue the currency to soften its domestic debt.
Of course in a country in which nobody honors their debt, there is no credit.
In the 1990s, the convertibility law not the currency board but the convertibility
law, made the difference. So did the decisions to have savings protected by dollars and the emphasis we put in
legislation on honoring obligations and fighting tax evasion. Our development in the 1990s was really financed
from domestic savings. And that permitted the incredible expansion of the banking system, from $10 billion up to
$80 billion, and the creation of the pension funds. This modernized much of the economy and created an increase
in productivity, particularly in traditional export sectors like agriculture.
"Two thirds of Argentinian bank assets were in debt to households or to the government,
which was borderline insolvent."
|
As for the next decade? If the old ideology that destroyed savings, prevented investment,
and generated inflation in the past, rules the day, then the first decade of the new century will be a lot like
the 1980s. The 1980s started with a default, and we struggled with foreign creditors. Eventually, it will wind
up in the complete collapse of the monetary and financial system through inflation.
Argentina has realized that the rules of the game of the 1990s were much superior to the
previous rules. The recent rule changes did not come about because the markets forced them. They were created by
big private sector debtors associated with the governors and with some politicians.
Building institutions is a very difficult political task. But I think these problems will
be fixed, because fortunately we have a republic. I think the judiciary will force the executive and the legislative
power to reverse many of the decisions that were adopted. The functioning of the constitutional system is more
important than any question related to the exchange rate system.
ROUBINI: There's no disagreement that institutions matter. But compare
Hong Kong and Argentina. They both had a currency board. Hong Kong in 1998 had a major shock. But there was no
budget deficit, no public debt problem, a very dynamic economy, and high productivity growth. They cut wages by
15 percent and that's how you achieve the real devaluation. In Argentina, you have a large public debt, a large
budget deficit, a current account deficit, and rigid labor markets. When you have a bunch of shocks, eventually
the regime collapses. So institutions mattered, but having also some policies mattered as well.
On convertibility, I'll be really blunt. I think they lived under the delusion that one
peso was one dollar. You know these currencies tend to collapse, so one peso is worth much less than a dollar.
What
s more, the peso-based assets were loans made to a government that was bankrupt. So the idea that a dollar in a
Buenos Aires bank is the same thing as a dollar in Miami or New York was a false idea.
CAVALLO: I
d argue that the illusion that Argentina had that we were saving dollars is exactly the same illusion that people
in Texas had that they were saving in dollars after the collapse of the price of oil in the late 1980s.
"The idea that a
dollar in a Buenos Aires bank is the same thing as a dollar in Miami or New York was a false idea."
|
ROUBINI: But that's why all those savings and loans and oil companies
went bankrupt in Texas.
CAVALLO: But they went bankrupt in spite of the fact that the dollar was
the American currency. If relative prices go down like if the price of oil plummets of course all the sectors
whose income is tied to those prices will have a problem. You can
t solve that with any monetary regime.
BLEJER: Saved in pesos, in dollars, or in chewing gum, the banking crisis
would have happened because the government was crowding out the private sector. The government was pushing bonds
into the banking sector. And this has nothing to do with the exchange rate.
CAVALLO: He
s right. We created the climate for getting a lot of financing from our citizens, because they were convinced that
they were saving dollars and that their savings were protected. They left their savings in the country and that
generated credit. But if this facility for credit simply allows the government to raise funds, and the government
wastes those resources and accumulates debt, of course it
s bad. The question is how to keep the savings and create credit while also protecting property rights of the people.
The answer is to impose discipline on the fiscal sector to prevent the misuse of those savings.
BLEJER: Without macro-economic stability you are not going to have investment
and growth. Argentina has paid a tremendous high price for this crisis, no doubt. Today more than 50 percent of
the population lives below the poverty line, 25 percent are below what's called extreme poverty. Unemployment is
22 percent. I think that there is basic agreement in the fact that one needs to rebuild a different framework,
but at the same time one has to be very careful to implement macro-economic policies that are conducive to the
recuperation of confidence of credibility.