In
the past year, the stock prices of telecommunications companies
have fallen sharply. Indeed, the shares of telephone companies,
once regarded as boring but dependable, have of late displayed
the volatility more common among software companies and Internet
retailers. For example, AT&T, once the ultimate widows-and-orphans
stock, lost half its value in 2000. Just two years after investing
in cable TV assets, CEO C. Michael Armstrong is now planning
to break AT&T into several parts.
|
n
the meantime, a series of mergers by local telephone companies
the Baby Bells created after the 1980s government-mandated break-up
of AT&T has led to a substantial remonopolization of the
telecommunications sector. Add in the cross-media AOL-TimeWarner merger,
the rapid growth of the Internet, and the stratospheric bids for European
spectrum to be used for wireless telecommunications, and the tele-communications
landscape is both confusing and treacherous to investors.
Why are
these once-reliable companies seeing their fortunes shift dramatically?
And why have so many shrewd investors been caught unaware by the plummeting
stock prices?
At the most
basic level, the stocks of some telecommunications companies fell
sharply in 2000 because the Internet- and technology-related investment
bubble was finally pricked. As investors realized that early expectations
for Internet growth were much higher than justified, stock valuations
were appropriately adjusted.
But the
deeper answer to why AT&T is breaking up while its former offspring
are acquiring each other lies in an understanding of the new market
dynamics created by advances in technology, and of successive government
attempts to stimulate competition through the enactment of new regulatory
schemes.
First, a
bit of history. For the past four decades, rapid technological change
in computers and transmission technology has consistently driven production
costs of telecommunications services steeply downwards. At the same
time, the regulatory environment, which was established to protect
consumers from monopolistic abuses, instead kept most of the benefits
of technological change from reaching consumers. For decades, in fact,
telecommunications services price decreases have been much slower
than cost decreases. In other words, companies did not exactly rush
to pass on the full benefits of rapid technological change to their
customers in the form of lower prices.
For
decades, telecommunications services price decreases have
been much slower than cost decreases. In other words,
companies did not exactly rush to pass on the full benefits
of rapid technological change to their customers in the
form of lower prices.
|
|
he
1981 government-imposed breakup, which created Seven Baby Bells to
provide local service and left parent Ma Bell (AT&T) as a long-distance
provider, was intended to remedy this state of affairs. By allowing
companies other than AT&T to compete in the then lucrative long-distance
market, the breakup did indeed create huge benefits to consumers.
The advent and growth of long-distance players like MCI (later WorldCom)
and Sprint lowered rates, to the point where residential and business
customers now pay long-distance rates that are a small fraction of
the 1981 price.
However,
the AT&T breakup had another effect that was less beneficial for
consumers. It fossilized the monopoly status of the seven local telephone
companies that were carved out of AT&T: Ameritech, Bell Atlantic,
Bell South, NYNEX, Pacific Bell, Southwestern Bell, and U.S. West.
To be sure, prices did fall dramatically for long-distance rates.
But they didnt fall quite as much as technological change and
competition would imply. Thats because the local telephone companies
the so-called Baby Bells were allowed to charge access
fees that were as much as ten times greater than cost to let
long-distance calls travel the last mile along their lines
to the consumer. As part of the 1981 AT&T breakup, local telephone
monopolies were barred from entering the long- distance market since
their huge access fees would have given them the ability to undercut
long-distance prices and easily drive the long-distance providers
out of business.
Fifteen
years after the AT&T break-up, the government again tried to remedy
the competitive situation through a sweeping action. The Telecommunications
Act of 1996 was supposed to level the playing field by allowing competition
in local markets. Once that happened, the local monopolies could compete
with their former parent in offering long-distance service.
However,
things havent quite worked out as intended. Five years after
the passage of the landmark legislation, less than four percent of
the local telecommunications market belongs to new entrants. Instead,
each of the eight large local monopoly telephone companies at the
AT&T 1981 breakup the seven Baby Bells plus GTE
continues to control more than 96% of its market. As important, these
firms have consolidated with one another, to the point where there
are now only four large local telecommunications monopolies: Bell
Atlantic, NYNEX, and GTE merged to form Verizon; Southwestern Bell,
Ameritech, and Pacific Bell got together to form SBC Communi-cations;
U.S. West was acquired by Qwest, and Bell South remains independent.
The Telecommunications
Act of 1996 ordered the local telephone companies to lease parts of
their network to new entrants, so that competition would take place
in local markets. But the local telephone companies have failed to
do so. And this has led to the substantial failure of the Telecommunications
Act of 1996, as well as to the demise of the hopes of long-distance
companies to become major competitors in local markets. It does appear
likely that local telephone companies such as Verizon may eventually
be permitted to offer long-distance service as Verizon already
does in New York State and therefore be able to sell both local
and long-distance service to the same customer. But it seems very
unlikely that long-distance companies will be able to capture significant
market shares in local markets by leasing parts of the local telecommunications
companies networks.
Five
years after the passage of the landmark 1996 legislation,
less than four percent of the local telecommunications
market belongs to the new entrants.
|
|
his
state of affairs helps explain AT&Ts strategic moves of
the past few years. Facing great difficulty in entering local markets
under the terms of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, AT&T CEO
C. Michael Armstrong decided two years ago to get into the local telephone
markets through broadband cable television connections. In other words,
it would offer local service through the high-capacity coaxial cables
that run into millions of American homes. Thus, AT&T spent billions
of dollars acquiring cable television companies TCI and MediaOne,
as well as a stake in TimeWarner. With a deep-pocketed and aggressive
firm on the scene, and with the ability to offer telephone service
over cable wires, it appears likely there could now be substantial
competition in local telephone service. As an added benefit, the cable
TV connection gives AT&T the possibility to sell high capacity
Internet service and other broadband services, such as interactive
video.
Given this
set of circumstances, it may seem contradictory for AT&T to even
consider divesting its cable television and wireless assets. Has the
company lost its nerve and vision? I think not. AT&Ts divestiture
plan was formed in response to pressure from financial markets and
large institutional shareholders. Despite its strategic moves and
large investments in cable TV assets, financial markets apparently
continued to value AT&T stock as if it were only a long-distance
telephone company. Moreover, long-distance prices have been under
tremendous pressure because a great deal of network transmission capacity
was built up by several competitors over the last three years due
to rampant Internet growth in the United States.
Thus, management
came to believe that the value of AT&T as a sum of the values
of its independent parts (cable-broadband, wireless, business services,
and residential long distance) is indeed higher than the present value
of the unified AT&T.
But if it
makes good financial and strategic sense for AT&T to break itself
into several parts once again, what is driving the seemingly contradictory
mergers of the local telephone companies that emerged from the 1981
AT&T breakup?
t
the 1981 AT&T breakup, the local telephone companies were allowed
to remain monopolists in the local markets. The 1996 Telecommunications
Act attempted to create competition in local markets and failed. Presently
the local telephone companies are poised to enter the long-distance
market without significant decreases of their market shares in local
markets. Looking forward to the time when they will be allowed to
sell long-distance services, local telephone companies have merged
to expand their customer base footprint and become stronger competitors
in the next battle among carriers that sell both local and long-distance
services. Twenty years after the government broke up the longstanding
MA Bell monopoly, the remonopolization of telecommunications is almost
here.
Nicholas
Economides is professor of economics at NYU Stern.
For more
on these issues, see Professor Economides Economics of Networks
website, http://www.stern.nyu.edu/networks, which has been ranked
by The Economist as one of the top five economics sites on the Internet.