Stocks
in emerging markets tend to move in the same direction while those
in developed markets tend to follow divergent paths. Why?
When
asked to predict activity in the stock market, J.P. Morgan replied
that stock prices would fluctuate. Modern finance theory ascribes
meaning to these fluctuations. The stocks of successful, well-run,
or lucky companies rise. Those of unsuccessful, misgoverned, or
unlucky companies fall. While portfolio managers view the volatility
of individual stocks as a problem to be overcome through diversification,
corporate executives watch their stocks rise or fall with euphoria
or dismay. A soaring stock price helps a company grow, by raising
bond ratings and bringing in more money from additional share
offerings. A plummeting stock price unsettles creditors and raises
the dilution cost of each dollar of new equity.
|
his
realignment of stock prices and, more importantly, the redirection of
capital flows that it causes, are thought to underlie the growth and prosperity
of modern free market economies. An economy that invests capital in poorly
run or ill-conceived enterprises cannot provide as high a standard of
living as an economy that puts capital where it is most useful. That this
mechanism works well is a prime argument by those who oppose government
intervention in the economy. That stock fluctuations are a meaningless
throw of dice is a prime argument made by those who mistrust capitalism
and all it stands for.
In a recent study, we uncovered
a puzzling regularity in the fluctuations of stock prices across the
markets of different countries. In the United States, and most other
developed countries, stocks tend to move in a relatively unsynchronized
manner. Ford rises, while GM simultaneously falls, for example. But
stocks in emerging markets, like those of Latin America, Asia, and Eastern
Europe, exhibit a uniformly different sort of volatility. In contrast
to the action in developed countries, stocks in emerging markets tend
to move up or down together en masse.
We began by analyzing stock
returns data from the first 26 weeks in 1995 to measure the degree of
price synchronicity in some representative stock markets. We calculated
the fraction of stocks that moved in the same direction in a given country,
filtered out those whose prices didnt move, and charted the number
that rose and fell. As seen in Table 1, in emerging markets like China
and Poland, over 80% of stocks often moved in the same direction in
a given week. For example, in China over 70% of stocks moved in the
same direction in 18 weeks. In Poland, 100% of traded stocks moved in
the same direction during four of the 26 weeks, and 70% moved in the
same direction in 20 weeks. By contrast, Denmark, Ireland, and the United
States lacked any instances in which more than 57% of the stocks moved
in the same direction during any week.
We then correlated the
full 1995 year price movements with the size of a countrys per
capita Gross Domestic Product between 1992 and 1994. Per capita GDP,
of course, is a general measure of economic development. But it can
also serve as a proxy for the economic structures and attributes that
make up developed economies. And we found that, in general, high-income
countries have asynchronous stock prices, with the U.S. having the lowest
fraction of stocks moving together. In contrast, low-income economies
have higher degrees of price synchronicity, with Poland, China, Taiwan,
Malaysia, and Turkey leading the pack. A closer look at the data reveals
that the nations we investigated grouped themselves into two data clusters:
high-income countries with low synchronicity and low-income countries
with high synchronicity.
Why should there be such
a difference between the fluctuations we see in the stock markets of
high and low income countries? We considered several possible explanations.
First, firms in low-income countries might have more correlated fundamentals.
After all, low-income economies tend to be small, undiversified, subject
to unstable macroeconomic policy, and characterized by intercorporate
equity cross-holdings. All these factors can turn events that affect
one industry into market-wide events. Second, low-income economies usually
provide poor and uncertain protection of private property rights. If
this reduces the transparency of companies in these countries to investors,
the fine tuning of individual companies stock prices that we see
in developed economy markets might not happen. If so, the stock markets
of these countries might be failing in their primary social task, the
allocation of capital.
We concluded that measures
of fundamentals correlation do not explain our finding, but that measures
of private property rights protection do. Indeed, variables like market
size, country size, economic diversification, macroeconomic policy stability,
and intercorporate earnings correlation are, at best, only vaguely related
to stock price asynchronicity. The measures of development that are
most closely related to stock price asynchronicity are measures of the
integrity of government, the efficiency of the judicial system, and
the rule of law.
Economic Explanations
To determine what explains
the highly significant negative correlation between stock price synchronicity
and per capita GDP, we investigated which particular development measures
are most correlated with stock price synchronicity.
irst,
we considered several possible economic explanations. The negative correlation
between stock price co-movement and per capita income could be due to
the fact that the companies in low-income economies tend to have more
correlated economic fundamentals. Or, it could be that unstable market
fundamentals are caused by macro-economic instability erratic
or unpredictable growth. In such economies, volatile market fundamentals
may overwhelm variations due to firm-specific factors, so that stock
prices tend to move together.
Table 1:
Click for larger image
|
Another factor could be
country size. Since economic activity in small countries is geographically
localized, nearby geopolitical instability or environmental catastrophes
like earthquakes might have market-wide effects that would not be as
evident in a larger country. For example, Finlands economy shrank
by 15% in the early 1990s as the neighboring Soviet Union disintegrated
and Finlands role as a gateway to Russia temporarily lost value.
In addition, stocks in large countries might move more independently
than those in small countries because of industrial and economic diversity.
For example, if oil prices fall, the prospects of Ohio manufacturing
firms brighten, while those of Texas oil companies dim. In contrast,
stocks in a smaller oil-producing country, like Venezuela, might move
more synchronously as oil prices change. In some economies, listed firms
could be concentrated in just a few industries, which tend to move in
sync. And since the stock markets in some economies may be dominated
by a few very large companies, a high degree of stock price synchronicity
may result if most other listed firms are suppliers or customers of
these dominant firms.
We tested these factors
by constructing indexes to stand as proxies for the variables and by
using regression analysis on our data. And we found some intriguing
results. For example, price synchronicity is negatively correlated with
a countrys geographical size the bigger the country is,
the less likely it is that its stocks move together. We also found that
price synchronicity is positively correlated with both GDP growth variance
and earnings co-movement. However, these correlations are all statistically
insignificant. And we found that greater economic and industrial diversity
is not consistently correlated with less stock price synchronicity.
So clearly, our basic result cannot be due simply to the fact that low-income
countries tend to be small and undiversified. Overall, in fact, these
correlations suggest that no one structural variable, on its own, satisfactorily
explains the link between per capita GDP and stock price synchronicity.
We checked to see if these structural variables, acting in concert,
might explain the link. But these results were similarly inconclusive.
Another Explanation: Institutional Development
After looking at these
economic development measures, we turned to measures of institutional,
legal, and political development. In many countries, after all, governments
and courts serve as mercantilist devices for diverting wealth to an
entrenched elite. Through legislation, licensing requirements, and nationalization,
government can inhibit the growth and development of businesses. In
these environments, political events, or even rumors about political
events, may cause large market-wide stock price swings and generate
high levels of stock price synchronicity. Scholar Ray Fisman in 1999
estimated that as much as 25% of the market value of many Indonesian
firms was related to political connections. This conclusion was based
on an analysis of stock price movements in response to rumors about
President Suhartos health.
Table 2:
Click for larger image
|
ndeed,
bad government might increase stock price synchronicity through channels
that are not directly associated with economic fundamentals, like corporate
earnings or GDP. Finance theory holds that professional investors
risk arbitrageurs expend resources to uncover proprietary information
about stocks and earn an acceptable return by using that information
to trade against less-informed investors. Such trading by many risk
arbitrageurs, each possessing unique proprietary information, is thought
to capitalize information into share prices of individual companies.
But risk arbitrage of this
sort may be less economically attractive in countries that protect private
property rights more poorly. Economic fundamentals can be obscured by
political factors in many low-income countries. Political events may
be hard to forecast in low-income nations whose governments are often
relatively opaque and erratic. And risk arbitrageurs who do make correct
predictions may not be allowed to keep their earnings. Because firm-specific
risk arbitrage could be relatively unattractive in such countries, informed
trading might be correspondingly thin.
If weak property rights
discourage informed risk arbitrage, they might also create systematic
stock price fluctuations. Scholars believe that an insufficient level
of informed trading can create space for noise trading
trading that reacts to political events, rumors, and the like. Once
the proportion of noise traders in the market rises above a critical
level, it might crowd out risk arbitrageurs, who are more risk-averse.
As a result, a stock market without a sufficient amount of informed
trading could be characterized by large systematic price swings
in other words, greater price synchronicity.
Measuring Good Government
If including a measure
of good government in our regression analysis renders per capita GDP
insignificant, that might be evidence that a lack of property rights
protection underlies the high degree of stock price synchronicity. To
capture the extent to which a countrys politicians respect private
property rights, we constructed a good government index as the sum of
three indexes from the International Country Risk Guide (ICR). The corruption
index is an assessment of corruption in government. Low scores
indicate that high government officials are likely to demand special
payments and that businesspeople may have to pay bribes in order
to get import and export licenses, loans, or tax assessments. The risk
of expropriation index gauges the risk of outright confiscation
or forced nationalization. The repudiation of contracts by government
index measures the risk of a modification in a contract
taking the form of a repudiation, postponement, or scaling down
due to budget cutbacks, indigenization pressure, a change in government,
or a change in government economic and social priorities.
he
good government index, like our synchronicity measures, tends to be
quite high for developed countries and quite low for emerging economies.
The results show that better protection of private property rights explains
stock price synchronicity, so much so that its inclusion renders per
capita GDP insignificant in explaining synchronicity. In addition, countries
with higher per capita incomes have higher good government indices.
And the good government index is significantly correlated with market
size, a finding that is consistent with more institutionally advanced
economies having markets on which more stocks trade. We also found that
the good government index remains significantly negatively correlated
with stock price synchronicity even after controlling for market size
and the structural variables.
Haves and Have-Nots
Our result leads to a conjecture
that the presence of a non-corrupt government that honors and respects
private property rights makes it attractive to conduct informed risk
arbitrage which results in more informed stock prices. Without an institutional
environment that honors property rights, informed risk arbitrage recedes
and noise trading generates large systematic swing in all stock prices
that is not closely related to economic fundamentals.
The good government
index, however, is a measure of institutional development. It is unlikely
to have a fine-grained incremental impact on the matter. Indeed, our
data tends to group into two clusters: high-income countries with low
stock price synchronicity and low-income countries with high synchronicity.
Substituting the good government index for per capita GDP also clearly
reveals two clusters. And this clustering suggests the possibility of
a threshold effect. If institutional development, as measured by our
good government index, is below a critical level, a different regime
governs stock prices, and a high degree of synchronicity is observed.
We used the mean of the
good government index as the dividing line in creating these subsamples,
yielding a developed economy group of 22 countries and an emerging economy
subsample of 15 countries. Then, we tested whether our results hold
within both subsamples, or mainly describe differences between the two
subsamples.
Among emerging economies,
stock market synchronicity is not correlated with either the logarithm
of per capita GDP or the good government index. So overall, synchronicity
in the emerging markets is generally high but not much worsened by marginal
decline in the protection accorded private property. Interestingly,
as in our conjecture, higher stock price synchronicity in emerging economies
is mainly associated with greater systematic variation.
In the developed country
subsample, however, the situation is more complex. Synchronicity is
marginally higher when the good government index is lower. More importantly,
high synchronicity in developed countries is associated both with low
levels of firm-specific variation and high levels of market-wide variation.
This finding motivates a closer look at the developed countries to clarify
the determinants of stock price synchronicity there.
Capitalization of Firm-Specific Information
It is possible that a countrys
institutions might affect the relative amounts of firm-specific versus
market-wide information that are capitalized into stock prices set by
rationally informed risk arbitrageurs. In other words, certain attributes
might encourage people to place their bets on individual stocks rather
than the market as a whole.
Our focus is that, unlike
in emerging economies, lower synchronicity in developed economies is
associated with greater firm-specific variation. In China, for example,
the whole market tends to move up or down dramatically, and so stocks
move together. By contrast, in the U.S., stocks tend to move more independently
of one another. Scholars have concluded that most of the variation in
U.S. stock prices reflects the capitalization of proprietary firm-specific
information people processing the data they have about individual
companies to influence the stock price.
e
considered two factors that might make firm-specific risk arbitrage
more attractive in economies: (1) better accounting data; and (2) better
protection for public investors from corporate insiders. If accounting
data are more useful, more firm-specific public information is available
to all investors. And that may let risk arbitrageurs make more precise
predictions regarding firm-specific stock price movements. A lack of
respect for the property rights of public investors by controlling shareholders
might discourage risk arbitrage based on firm-level information and
hence impedes the capitalization of firm-level information in stock
prices in some developed countries.
To test these hypotheses,
we ran the numbers again using only data from developed countries in
our sample. First, we substituted a direct measure of the sophistication
of each countrys accounting standards in place of the good government
index. The measure was created by scholars based on 1990 data compiled
by the Center for International Financial Analysis and Research, Inc.
And when we did, it turned out that good accounting standards are negatively
correlated with synchronicity. But since the significance levels are
in the neighborhood of 20%, the accounting standards index itself is
uniformly statistically insignificant.
Next, we employed a direct
measure of the extent to which public shareholders property is
protected from appropriation by corporate insiders the anti-director
rights index. This index is a scorecard of shareholders rights
against directors in various countries. For such rights to provide effective
protection, a country must have functional political and legal systems.
It is therefore plausible that the anti-director rights index might
be relevant only in countries where the rule of law prevails. Notice
that among countries with strong property rights protections in general
there exists quite a bit of variation in protecting the property rights
of public investors against corporate insiders.
We therefore ran regressions
substituting the anti-director rights index for the good government
index. We found that while the anti-director rights index is insignificant
in the whole sample and emerging economy subsample, it is negative and
highly statistically significant in the developed economy subsample.
Numbing the Invisible Hand?
So what do we conclude
from these results? Yes, stock returns are more synchronous in emerging
economies than in developed economies. But while some economic characteristics
may contribute to stock return synchronicity, they dont entirely
explain the outcome. Rather, it seems that the level of institutional
development is highly correlated with stock price synchronicity.
In particular, less respect
for private property by government is associated with more market-wide
stock price variation, and therefore also with more synchronous stock
price movements. Since these market-wide price fluctuations are uncorrelated
with fundamentals, we conjecture that poor property rights protection
might deter informed risk arbitrage and noise traders create arbitrary
fluctuations. However, we would welcome other possible explanations.
In developed economies,
providing public shareholders with stronger legal protection against
corporate insiders is associated with lower synchronicity. We conjecture
that economies that protect public investors property rights might
discourage intercorporate income-shifting by controlling shareholders.
Better property rights protection thus might render risk-arbitrage based
on firm-specific information more attractive, which leads to asynchronous
stock price movements.
Overall, our results suggest
that stock markets in emerging economies may be less useful as processors
of economic information than stock markets in advanced economies. The
function of an efficient stock market is to process information, and
thereby guide capital towards its best economic use. But stock price
movements in emerging economies are mainly due to either politically
driven shifts in property rights or noise trading; numb invisible hands
in their stock markets may allocate capital poorly, thereby retarding
economic growth.
Randall Morck is Stephen
A. Jarislowsky distinguished professor of finance at the University
of Alberta.
Bernard Yeung is Abraham
Krasnoff professor of international business and professor of economics
at NYU Stern.
This article is adapted
from an article in the Journal of Financial Economics, October 2000
Volume 58, pp. 215-260.