
The 20th centurys
theorist
of 21st-century
entrepreneurship


anagement
journals and New Economy magazines are filled with an unending
stream of thinking and writing about entrepreneurship. But amid
the proliferation of management gurus, theres one theorist
whose voice pierces through the clutter: Joseph Schumpeter. More
than a half-century ago, the Moravia-born economist coined the
enduring term creative destruction as a great metaphor
for capitalism. But his understanding of the dynamics of capitalism
and the role of entrepreneurs are just as salient and incisive
today as they were when he first made them. |
orn
in 1883, Schumpeter was educated at the Univer-sity of Vienna, where
he received degrees in law and political economy. From 1909 until
1911, he taught at the University of Czernowitz, where he wrote The
Theory of Economic Development, the 657-page foundation stone of his
theory of entrepreneurship. He taught at universities in Austria,
Germany, and Japan, worked as a lawyer in Egypt, briefly ran Austrias
finance ministry in 1919, and served unsuccessfully
as president of Viennas private Biederman Bank from 1921 until
1924. Meanwhile, he found time to indulge in a plethora of romantic
liaisons, of which he liked to boast. (He would marry three times.)
Schumpeter came to Harvard permanently in 1932, and became an American
citizen. He died in 1950.
|
Between 1905 and 1950, he produced 15 books,
six pamphlets, about 100 book reviews, and at least 148 articles
and comments. But it isnt just the quantity that impresses,
it is the quality.
|
A serious scholar
he had almost no recreation other than the occasional game
of tennis Schumpeter was one of the great polymaths of the
twentieth century. Between 1905 and 1950, he produced 15 books, six
pamphlets, about 100 book reviews, and at least 148 articles, and
comments. But it isnt just the quantity that impresses, it is
the quality. The intellectual historian Martin Kessler argues that
Schumpeter was, apart from John Maynard Keynes, the only truly
great economist the 20th century has produced. And business
historians like Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., regard Schumpeter as the
economist who best understood the rise of big business and the central
roles of innovation and entrepreneurship.
Unlike many famous scholars, Schumpeter exhibited a lively interest
in and respect for well-done work regardless of the disciplinary banner
under which it appeared. As his Harvard colleague Seymour Harris once
put it, Schumpeter was primarily an economist, but historians
and sociologists can include him as one of their stars too.
He held as an article of faith that all good economics must include
theory, history, and statistics. And he relentlessly evangelized in
favor of econometrics. Schumpeter helped organize the Econometric
Society and served as its president from 1937 to 1941.
Although his
work encompassed a wide range of subjects, it is his theory of entrepreneurship
a word and phenomenon with which his name will likely forever
be linked that is most relevant to contemporary business practitioners.
Schumpeter developed his innovative theories in three main books:
The Theory of Economic Development (1911), Business Cycles (1939),
and Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy (1942).
The Theory
of Economic Development
In the early 20th century, economic thought was dominated by theorists
who posited that economic systems were fueled by a circular
flow of inputs and outputs, and were generally at a state of
equilibrium. But Schumpeter found that this traditional economic analysis
lacked a workable theory of innovation or finance i.e. a realistic
model of the way saving and investment actually operate in a dynamic
economic system.
In his 1911 book Die Theorie der Wirstshaftlichen Entwicklung (the
English version, The Theory of Economic Development, did not appear
until 1934), Schumpeter set forth the first thoroughgoing exposition
of a more complex system. In his new model, economic routine is periodically
interrupted by entrepreneurial behavior that comes in clusters and
disrupts equilibrium. Entrepreneurs, who could effectively function
as free agents, unconnected to a single firm, disrupt the circular
flow by carrying out new combinations. This, he asserts,
is the basis of economic development, and embodies the essence of
capitalism.
In an effort to divine the motivations of entrepreneurs, Schumpeter
departed from economics and dipped into the realm of psychology. The
typical entrepreneur is more self-centered than other types, because
he relies less than they do on tradition and connection and because
his characteristic task consists precisely in breaking up old, and
creating new, tradition, he wrote. An entrepreneur is motivated
by the dream and the will to found a private kingdom.
Other motivations, he wrote, include the will to conquer,
the impulse to fight, and the joy of creating.
Schumpeter also saw profound sociological implications in the rise
of some entrepreneurs and the obsolescence of others. Just as businesses
rise and fall, so too do entrepreneurs and their families. Or as he
put it in one of his many great metaphors, the upper strata
of [a capitalist] society are like hotels which are indeed always
full of people, but people who are forever changing. Schumpeter
also noted that just as intellectual entrepreneurs proposing new theories
face opposition, business entrepreneurs seeking to overthrow conventional
wisdom encounter resistance from entrenched interests. Those whose
positions are threatened by innovation, he wrote, may be expected
to fight innovation, even to organize against it by throwing up legal
and political impediments.
The last vital
element in the system Schumpeter delineates in The Theory of Economic
Development in what he calls the swarm-like appearance of entrepreneurs,
which represents the kickoff of a new business cycle under capitalism.
He relates his theory of entrepreneurial activity directly to what
was for his generation the most difficult analytical problem posed
by capitalist economies: the jerky disturbance of the
equilibrium position, as Schumpeter himself calls it
not any gentle ebb and flow, but rather a disturbance of a different
order of magnitude. It was to the mysteries of such disturbances
that Schumpeter would devote his next big book, Business Cycles (1939).
Business Cycles
Some 27 years
elapsed between the publication of The Theory of Economic Development
and the 1939 appearance of Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical,
and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process. During those years
Schumpeter experienced multiple personal traumas: living through World
War I and its aftermath in Austria, fleeing Germany, and losing his
family. By 1939, he had become deeply pessimistic about the state
of the world.
He came to believe that capitalism contains
the seeds of its own destruction not for economic reasons
but for sociological ones.
|
|
A book with grand ambitions, the 1,100-page, two-volume work nonetheless
proved a monumental disappointment to Schumpeters many admirers
and to the author himself. It was thoroughly upstaged by Keyness
General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, which appeared
in 1936. Schumpeter did not work well with editors, and was loath
to show work-in-progress even to his professional colleagues, let
alone to seek editorial advice. As a result, his work was repetitive
and undisciplined; his aversion to the editorial may have limited
his influence among the larger public.
In Business
Cycles, Schumpeter again set about to marry multiple disciplines.
He tried to turn cyclical economic patterns into predictive scientific
wave theories borrowed from physics. The book is also imbued with
a remarkable richness of historical detail and understanding. Although
the technical explanation of cycles remained problematical, the historical
vision that underlay Schumpeter's effort at synthesis was squarely
on point: that capitalism not all economic activity, just capitalism
is fundamentally an unstable, disequilibrating process. Despite
its sophistication, Business Cycles sold only about 1,500 copies.
Capitalism,
Socialism, and Democracy
The failure of Business Cycles may have informed Schumpeters
next book, Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, which was published
in 1942. It is as though the author, now deeply pessimistic not only
about the indifferent reception of Business Cycles but also about
the state of the world, decided to unburden himself on an array of
other subjects in addition to economics narrowly construed.
Despite the books title, it contains little of lasting interest
about either socialism or democracy. But it bursts with ideas about
capitalism, and as a performance a term Schumpeter
liked to apply to others works it may be the best analysis
of capitalism ever written. It was here that Schumpeter first coined
the oxymoronic phrase creative destruction, which quickly
took second place only to Adam Smiths invisible hand
in the history of a discipline already rich in memorable metaphors.
Schumpeters core argument in Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy
is reducible to three major tenets:
1. The essence of capitalism is innovation (creative destruction)
in particular sectors. Certain standard tools of economics, such as
static equilibrium and macroeconomic analysis, are useful; but carried
too far they can disguise reality and mislead scholars and students.
2. The virtues
of capitalism in particular its steady but gradual pattern
of growth are long-run and hard to see; its defects, such as
inequality, apparent monopoly, and wild gyrations in the business
cycle, are short-run, conspicuous, and directly hurtful to important
interest groups.
|
Pushing his analysis to its limits, Schumpeter
further identifies capitalist entrepreneurship with technological
progress itself.
|
3. It is dangerous for economists to prescribe general
recipes and nostrums for reform, because political and social circumstances
are always changing.
In many ways, Business Cycles was a synthesis. Some of the major themes
of Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy represent reworkings of ideas
Schumpeter had first presented in articles published long before,
while in his twenties (he was 59 in 1942, when the book appeared).
Others came directly out of Business Cycles. A capitalist economy,
he now wrote, is not and cannot be stationary. Nor is it merely
expanding in a steady manner. Every situation is being upset before
it has had time to work itself out. Economic progress, in capitalist
society, means turmoil.
The contemporary structure of business, Schumpeter argues, is best
understood as having evolved from a long organizational development.
It reflects a process of industrial mutation if I may
use that biological term that incessantly revolutionizes the
economic structure from within, incessantly destroying the old one,
incessantly creating a new one. In sum, the process is one of
creative destruction the sweeping out of old products,
old enterprises, and old organizational forms by new ones. It
is what capitalism consists in and what every capitalist concern has
got to live in.
It may sound relatively mild to the contemporary ear. But with these
radical declarations, Schumpeter was, in effect, indicting the entire
profession of mainstream economics for failing to acknowledge that
continuous innovation is endogenous to capitalism. Pushing his analysis
to its limits, Schumpeter further identifies capitalist entrepreneurship
with technological progress itself. As a matter of historical record,
they were essentially one and the same thing, the first
being the propelling force of the second.
These vital statements led Schumpeter to a somewhat more pessimistic
conclusion. For he came to believe that capitalism contains the seeds
of its own destruction not for economic reasons but for sociological
ones. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy delves deeply into sociology
to describe the ways in which capitalism undermined the traditional
underpinnings of civilized society and created new economic orders,
which in turn sets off recurring cycles of creative destruction. Capitalism
is so successful economically, he wrote, that it creates, educates
and subsidizes a vested interest in social unrest. He concludes,
in the end, by professing to see not only the decline of capitalism
but also the ultimate triumph of socialism. Can capitalism survive?
he asked. No. I do not think it can.
When Capitalism,
Socialism, and Democracy was first published in 1942, it received
a modicum of attention, probably because World War II was dominating
not only the news but intellectual and economic life as well. A second
edition, which appeared in 1946, attracted wider notice. But the third
edition, published in 1950 at a high point in the Cold War, when capitalism
and socialism were, in fact, competing furiously for the worlds
allegiance, became an international best-seller. It produced thousands
of future citations by scholars in sociology, history, economics,
and other disciplines. Translated into at least 16 languages, Business
Cycles still sells widely in paperback editions.
Creative Destruction
and Entrepreneurship
Of course, Schumpeter turned out to be incorrect. Several decades
after his death, it was capitalism that ultimately triumphed over
socialism not the other way around. But the lasting value of
Schumpeters work lies not in his accuracy as a prognosticator,
but in his brilliant analysis of how entrepreneurs work, and in his
ability to change the way economists, students, and practitioners
write and think about entrepreneurship and technological change.
Schumpeters
work began to find a wider audience during the 1960s and 1970s, and
a still broader one in the last two decades of the 20th century. In
the years after his death, scholars began to analyze not only the
process of creation, but also the destruction that was its inevitable
concomitant. They wondered about the human costs of economic progress,
and started to rethink the nature of human existence under capitalism.
They turned their thoughts to the inescapable tradeoffs between economic
values on the one hand and social ones on the other.
Has there ever been a more penetrating analyst
of capitalism in all its dimensions than Joseph Schumpeter?
No, I do not think there has.
|
|
In the 1980s and 1990s, the demise of command economies in eastern
and central Europe and the remarkable economic performance of China
and other Asian countries raised perplexing questions about the relationship
between capitalism on the one hand and democracy on the other.
At the same time, in many business schools, perhaps most notably Harvard
and Babson, entrepreneurial studies took off. Masses of students began
to express interest in the subject and to demand curricula. The total
number of business schools with offerings in entrepreneurially-oriented
courses soared from six in 1967 to 370 by 1993.
At the Harvard Business School, where in the late 1940s Schumpeter
had helped to set up the Research Center in Entrepreneurial History,
enrollment in elective courses offered by the newly organized Entrepreneurial
Management Unit reached more than 1,100 in 1996. In 1999, the School's
administration introduced a new course entitled The Entrepreneurial
Manager into the required curriculum.
Meanwhile, in the United States, and to a lesser extent in Western
Europe, the phenomenal run-up of securities markets throughout the
1990s piqued sharp new interest in the entrepreneurs who became dot-com
millionaires and billionaires. In this new setting, Schumpeters
work on entrepreneurship acquired a compelling new interest. Scholars
from many disciplines began to find in his writings either answers
to their own questions or valuable maps and guidebooks for new avenues
of research. During the 1990s, the number of academic citations to
Schumpeters works actually overtook those to Keyness,
a phenomenon that would have seemed inconceivable a generation earlier.
In the end, the fundamental reason for the ongoing relevance of Schumpeter
to the study of business and social science comes down to his passionate
insistence on the indivisibility of intellectual inquiry, together
with the sheer fertility and power of his mind.
Has there ever
been a more penetrating analyst of capitalism in all its dimensions
than Joseph Schumpeter? No, I do not think there has.
Thomas McCraw,
the Isidor Straus professor of business history at Harvard Business
School, is editor of the Business History Review. Last spring, the
Pulitzer Prize winner was the entrepreneurship scholar-in-residence
at NYU Sterns Berkley Center for Entrepreneurial Studies.