


The escalating pace of change over the last
few years has introduced new terms such as hypercompetition,
disruptive technology, and new economy into the business vernacular.
This high-growth, high-risk world of continuous discontinuity
reflects the transformational power of entrepreneurship and
technological innovation a dynamic anticipated over half
a century ago by Joseph Schumpeter, the famed Austrian-born
economist whose ideas about capitalism have made him a 21st
century superstar.
|
chumpeter
portended the new economy in his seminal book
Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (1942). He believed new technologies
and combinations that disrupt the prevailing equilibrium
were the key to long-term growth and the development of capitalist
economies not the steady accumulation of capital stock, as
economic orthodoxy held. The process of industrial mutation,
he wrote, incessantly revolutionizes the economic structure
from within, incessantly destroying the old one, incessantly creating
a new one. Schumpeter dubbed this process creative destruction,
and argued that it was the essential fact about capitalism.
This idea is so powerful that even people who have never heard of
the long-deceased economist are familiar with the phrase he coined.
Schumpeter
was referring to the processes that influence the outcome of a collection
of companies rather than the processes that occur within a single
company. But creative destruction can take place in both a macro and
a micro setting. In a corporate setting the most dramatic acts of
destruction are the decisions to sell or shut down a division.
A milder form might be to spin off a business unit. The point of destruction
in these cases is, as Schumpeter implied, to make way for creation,
to refresh or renew the corporation.
But individual companies do not do
nearly as good a job of creative destruction as capital markets. Richard
Foster and Sarah Kaplan, co-authors of the recent book Creative Destruction,
argue that markets not corporations allow new companies
to enter more freely, and ruthlessly force the elimination of those
companies without competitive prospects. Moreover, markets change
much faster and on a larger scale than do corporations. Whereas markets
operate on the assumption of discontinuity and accommodate continuity,
corporations assume continuity and attempt to accommodate discontinuity.
These major differences pose a serious
threat to managers of even the most successful and well-established
corporations. Based on the results of a McKinsey & Co.-sponsored
study of more than 1000 companies in 15 industries over almost four
decades, Foster and Kaplan predict that by 2020 more than three quarters
of the S&P 500 will consist of new companies that will be drawn
into the maelstrom of economic activity from the periphery.
So, how can corporations make themselves
more like the market? The answer, according to Foster and Kaplan,
is to establish a more dynamic view that mandates managing creative
destruction first and operations second. But the corporation must
do so in a highly decentralized way, without sacrificing control.
This is easier said than done. Few
corporate leaders have the energy or time to manage the processes
of creative destruction, especially at the pace and scale necessary
to compete with the market.
Corporate Venturing
One answer that many have turned
to is corporate venturing. Corporate venturing is a practice that
aims to enable companies to successfully surf the waves of creative
destruction. It involves the development of an organized effort to
leverage existing assets and capabilities to help create new businesses.
It differs from other traditional business practices that facilitate
growth through access to new technology, such as acquisitions and
corporate research and development (R&D). New businesses developed
through corporate venturing are typically developed through an incubation
process rather than through acquisition and integration into the company.
Corporate venturing investments are usually riskier and less subject
to rigid management of internal costs than conventional R&D. In
fact, protecting venture investments from such controls is a key reason
why start-ups are organized separately from the ongoing corporate
business.
The history of corporate venturing
reflects an enduring corporate fascination with the success of venture
capital (VC) firms over the last forty years. Venture capitalists
are certainly not infallible; they are eminently capable of entering
markets too early or too late, picking the wrong start-up teams, and
riding some investments longer than they should. But over the past
twenty years, VC firms have done a far better job of embracing the
spirit of creative destruction than traditional operating companies.
In replacing the traditional assumption of continuity with the assumption
of discontinuity, they have become important drivers of change in
the worlds largest economy, created enormous wealth for their
investors, and shown how individual companies can create value at
the pace and scale of the market.
he
first corporate venture programs were inspired by the successes of
the VC firms that backed such start-ups as Digital Equipment and Raychem.
During the late 1960s and early 1970s, more than 25% of Fortune 500
firms had corporate venturing programs. Many were disbanded in the
second half of the 1970s following a severe decline in public market
and VC activity. Following dramatic growth in the VC market in the
early 1980s and the successes of firms that backed such smash hits
as Apple and Genentech, corporations again set up venturing programs.
By 1986, corporate venture capital represented 12% of total VC investing.
Many of these programs were again discontinued after the 1987 market
downturn and the ensuing dramatic drop in VC fundraising. Almost 40%
of corporate venturing programs were abandoned within four years of
their initiation. By 1992, corporate venture capital had fallen to
5% of total venture capital investing.
The second half of the 1990s brought
a third wave of venture capital success and inspiration. Fueled by
emerging technologies, opportunities posed by the Internet and a robust
economy, independent venture funds began to notch annual returns of
more than 50% after 1995. VC investment rebounded from an annual average
of $6 billion in the mid- 1980s to over $17 billion in 1998, and to
over $100 billion in 2000. And once again, corporate venturing programs
followed. Between 1995 and 1999, the number of U.S. companies that
made corporate venture investments increased from 62 to 415. According
to the research firm Venture Economics, corporate venture capital
activity soared from $542 million in 1996 to $1.1 billion in 1997,
$1.6 billion in 1998, $8.6 billion in 1999, and $16.5 billion in 2000.
The Track Record
Early studies of corporate venturing
programs, which took place in the 1980s and early 1990s, led many
to conclude that they were inherently unstable and unlikely to succeed.
Researchers observe such difficulties as building and sustaining internal
support for new ventures from top management, potential inherent conflicts
of interest arising between the sponsoring firm and the new venture,
and the inability of the corporation to provide an appropriate risk/reward
compensation to new venture managers.
But more recent empirical research
paints a much more positive picture of the value of corporate venturing
programs. In a study comparing over thirty thousand investments in
start-ups over a 15- year period, Professors Paul Gompers and Josh
Lerner found that corporate venture investments appear to be at least
as successful (using such measures as the probability of a portfolio
firm going public) as traditional venture capital firms. In another
study analyzing over 300 venture capital-backed, information technology
IPOs in 1998-1999, researchers Marku Maula and Gordon Murray demonstrated
that emerging technology companies performed better with corporate
equity investments than with traditional VC investors. The financial
involvement of Global Fortune 500 Infocom companies was
directly associated with higher first-day valuations. In both these
studies, success is correlated with the strategic fit between the
corporate parent or corporate investor and the venture.
Both the problems and successes in
corporate venturing can be traced to the fundamental difference between
such programs and independent venture capital. In contrast to VC firms,
which have financial returns as their fundamental goal, most companies
pursuing corporate venturing programs cite strategic returns as their
fundamental aim. Strategic returns include exposure to radically new
and disruptive technologies, access to new products and markets, and
identification of acquisition targets.
major
cause of corporate venturing failure is the desire to accomplish a
wide array of objectives that are not necessarily compatible. To maximize
financial returns, firms are best advised to emulate independent VC
firms. They need to provide complete autonomy to the new ventures
managers and to compensate risk-taking behavior with equity stakes.
They also need to exercise strict discipline by staging the financial
support pending the achievement of certain milestone events and by
providing intensive guidance and oversight without interfering with
the basic decision-making responsibilities of the entrepreneurs who
run the business. This includes a practiced indifference to potential
synergies or complementarities with other businesses in the corporate
portfolio.
Resolving Conflicts
But this posture can create conflicts.
By emulating such venture capital practices, firms negate the important
strategic mandate of corporate venturing programs. If the prime motivation
for the new venture is strategic, then providing greater autonomy,
a disproportionately higher compensation level, strict financial discipline
on the downside, and ignoring strategic complementarities will increase
the likelihood of potential conflict between the new venture and the
established business.
Given such conflicts, it is not enough
for corporate venturing programs to be managed more like private venture
capital. Instead, they must be hybrids. Corporate venturing programs
must be designed to benefit from certain practices employed by venture
capitalists, while at the same time leveraging structural advantages
to manage the development and commercialization of new technologies
that are not available to independent venture capital firms.
Lets take a few examples of
how this works. All investments made by private venture capital firms
are assumed to have a limited life typically seven to 10 years
or less. At the end of that time VCs are required to sell their investments
and return the capital to their limited partners. This limited horizon
creates an incentive alignment between limited partners and the venture
capital partners that encourages venture capitalists to invest only
when they have a clear idea about the pace and scale of the gains
that can be achieved. Corporations, on the other hand, do not face
the same pressure to produce liquidity events for new businesses.
As a result, they can fund and sustain longer-term projects, which
often involve the development of radical innovations and technological
breakthroughs.
A second important structural advantage
comes from the corporations ownership of important physical,
knowledge-based and intangible complementary assets that cannot be
freely traded in the external markets, like a companys brand
name or its reputation. In addition, certain technologies require
the coordination of complementary technologies in order to deliver
value. For example, last year Qualcomm, the wireless telephone company,
created a $500 million corporate venture fund to invest in start-ups
that develop wireless Internet applications particularly those
that will lead to the adoption of a technology for transmissions that
complements the standards employed by Qualcomm.
Finally, there is the potential learning
advantage companies gain from investing in new ventures even when
they fail. For example, 3M has developed a culture that not only tolerates
failure but has also institutionalized practices that facilitate learning
and knowledge transfer among employees involved in technological innovation.
Each of the investments made by Eastman Chemical Company this past
year led to the development of a strategic relationship that has given
the company access to early development of important technology.
Elements of Corporate Venturing
Strategy
So what can a corporation do to increase
its odds of succeeding at corporate venturing? First, it must be committed
to the mantra of creative destruction. Does senior management regularly
think about the companies that define the periphery of the industry?
Do they have the courage to shut down ventures that are not working
out? Is the company willing to let customer demand control how its
corporate venturing investments are allocated even if this means less
control over the direction the new venture will take?
 |
Second, senior management must decide
on the principal goals of the corporate venturing initiative. This
means more than declaring that the goals are primarily strategic.
It means identifying the specific type of goal and ensuring that multiple
goals are compatible. Does the corporation want to have access to
new technology that will lead to capitalizing on the next new,
new thing? Does it wish to invest in competing technologies
in which a dominant new standard is likely to emerge, but in which
the outcome is unclear? Does the company want to invest in start-ups
that will serve to promote demand for its core products? Or does the
company just want to expand its current R&D efforts by complementing
them with external investments?
Third, senior management must determine
whether it has the resources and talent necessary to carry out these
goals. Does it have employees with the requisite experience to lead
the initiative? Can it easily hire them? Does it have the capital
to finance the large investments that are required? Does it have a
culture that encourages the sharing of information across units?
Fourth, senior management must decide
on the appropriate design for the corporate venturing unit and its
governance. Corporations use a variety of structural forms to engage
in venturing. These forms reflect increasing corporate internalization
or involvement, and range from acting as a limited partner in venture
funds established by independent venture capitalists to creating a
corporate unit that makes direct investments in start-ups, some of
which are subsequently spun out as independent companies
while others are spun in as acquisitions. For example,
when Procter & Gambles new venture, Reflect.com, confronted
the corporations inability to provide it with necessary know-how
regarding the Internet and e-commerce, P&G opted to use an outsourced
model, in which the company worked in partnership with an independent
venture capital firm. P&G agreed to invest $35 million in the
Web business and keep a 65% equity stake, licensing its patented manufacturing
technology to Reflect.com. The independent venture capital firm agreed
to invest $15 million and take a 15% equity stake. Each party received
two seats on the board. Xerox, in contrast, has opted for a business
incubation model, forming a new entity Xerox New Enterprises
in 1996 to capture the value of Xerox technologies in a portfolio
of entrepreneurial companies with important document processing hardware
and software technologies in various stages of development.
wo
other important aspects of design involve the reporting structure
and the incentive system. Research suggests that to be successful,
a corporate venturing unit must have a high-level champion within
the corporation. To increase company-wide support, corporate venturing
units should have their managers report directly to the CEO or to
a key business-unit head. Designing incentive packages to be in line
with the market for venture capitalists as well as with the compensation
received by employee peers within the corporation poses an inherent
conflict. An effort should nevertheless be made to design an incentive
system that fits the goals of the corporate venturing initiative,
the risk/reward levels involved, and the length of the performance
horizon.
A New Wave
Given the boom and bust
history of corporate venturing that took place over the last forty
years, one cannot but wonder whether the recent economic downturn
and the ensuing meltdown among VC firms will lead once again to a
reduction in corporate venturing activity. There are certainly some
signs of retrenchment. During the first six months of 2001, a number
of major corporations disclosed that their venture capital portfolios
incurred significant losses. These include banking and investment
giants J.P. Morgan Chase & Co. and Wells Fargo, and leading computer
companies Compaq and Dell. Lucent Venture Partners, the venture capital
unit of Lucent Technologies, is now investing at a slower pace than
in years past because of the pull-back among the traditional VCs with
which Lucent co-invests. And Motorola Ventures, the venture capital
unit of Motorola, will be investing in fewer deals this year due to
a shift in investment strategy.
In general however, this go-around
appears to be different than past cycles. Companies such as Qualcomm,
Nokia, Eastman Chemical Corporation, UPS, General Mills, and even
Coca-Cola continued to invest aggressively, even in the dismal fourth
quarter of 2000 and the gloomy first quarter of 2001. Despite the
serious problems plaguing both Motorola and Lucent, neither company
has slated its corporate venturing programs for elimination. And while
Compaq recently shut down its corporate development office in the
wake of a company-wide restructuring, it still expects to make the
same number of venture deals through its existing business units.
he
most recent wave of corporate venturing activity reflects a much greater
focus on strategic benefits and much stronger long-term commitment
by parent companies. The dramatic reduction in funding by independent
venture capitalists during this time has created more opportunities
for corporations to invest. And the impressive track record of many
corporate venturing programs in helping early stage companies develop
has given them more credibility with entrepreneurs as well as conventional
VCs, who are now much less prone to viewing corporate venture capital
as dumb money.
Increasingly mindful of the disruptive
capabilities of new business entrants, managers of large corporations
are more aggressive than ever about winning the creative destruction
game. And they appear to have a much better grasp of the important
role of corporate venturing in creating opportunities for corporate
growth and renewal. Strong financial pressures will certainly force
some corporations to reorganize or downsize their corporate venturing
efforts. But savvy executives have come to understand that their companies
cannot afford to stop investing in innovation during an economic slowdown.
So while many VC firms continue to lick their wounds from the destructive
creation they helped generate among Internet start-ups, corporate
venturing has an unprecedented opportunity to drive the next wave
of technological change and economic growth.
Ari Ginsberg is Harold Price professor
of entrepreneurship and director of the Berkley Center for Entrepreneurial
Studies at NYU Stern.