

WANT TO FREE UP THE AIRWAVES FOR INNOVATION?
THINK OF THE SPECTRUM AS REAL ESTATE.
|

The electromagnetic spectrum can't be seen,
tasted, smelled, or touched. It isn't high on most people's
lists of daily concerns. But it is integral to the development
of modern telecommunications, including the broadband revolution
of information dissemination and retrieval.
|
nfortunately,
the spectrum is mired in a system of all-encompassing federal regulation
that sometimes makes the former Soviet Union look like a paragon of
efficiency. The time is long overdue for fundamental reform. The answer
lies not in reinventing government jargon, but in the simple language
of one of Americas oldest and most entrepreneurial sectors:
real estate. Only by propertyzing the spectrum
i.e., applying real-estate-like property rights to the spectrum
will we unleash the full potential of this immensely valuable but
invisible national resource.
The Spectrum
The spectrum encompasses all possible
frequencies of electromagnetic waves. The radio spectrum, which is
what needs reform, covers the range from 30 Hz (cycles per second)
to 300 GHz (billion cycles per second). These airwaves
are used for an ever expanding array of over-the-air electronic transmissions
and wireless devices radio and television broadcasting, cellular
phones, mobile radio, satellite communications, microwave cooking,
garage door openers. A large part of the broadband revolution
will occur through spectrum-based devices.
Different bands of the spectrum have
different characteristics that make them better or worse for various
uses. Some frequencies are better at long-distance transmission; others
are better at penetrating solid objects. And one persons use
of a portion of the spectrum can be easily interfered with by another
persons transmission use of the same wavelength, in the same
place, at the same time. Interference also occurs from incidental
transmissions originating in neighboring geographical locations or
spectrum bands and from extraneous sources such as sunspots, lightning,
electrical motors or generators, and transmission lines.
Spectrum Management and Mismanagement
In 1927, when interference chaos
threatened the nascent broadcasting industry, Congress and President
Calvin Coolidge who famously said the chief business of the
American people is business enacted a Soviet-style central
planning solution: The federal government would prevent interference
by making all spectrum allocation decisions. As a result, for the
past 74 years the spectrum has effectively been the property of the
American public, and the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) has
been charged with managing the spectrum in the public interest.
To this day, the FCC decides the use say, broadcasting, or
cellular phones, or garage door openers to which a specific
block of spectrum will be put. Then it defines the parameters of service,
such as transmitter power and location. The FCC grants a license to
a specific party to operate a transmitter over a specific frequency
ban, and then enforces its allocations, service rules, and assignments
to ensure that interference does not arise.

"The spectrum is mired in a system
of all-encompassing federal regulation that sometimes
makes the former Soviet Union look like a paragon of
efficiency."
|
|
|
In the 1920s, when the technology
was rudimentary and the possibilities were limited, this management
process was arguably tolerable: The early users of spectrum
radio broadcasters were like homesteaders: First-come, first-served
for a free renewable FCC spectrum license was an acceptable method
of assignment.
But since the 1920s, the technologies
of spectrum use have exploded. And as the rising value of the multiple
uses of the spectrum has become increasingly apparent, competitors,
in ever-larger numbers, have contended for the use of various spectrum
parcels.
The FCC has tried to adapt to the
changing climate. From the late 1920s until the late 1970s, if the
FCC concluded that, say, an additional AM radio station should be
broadcasting in Dubuque, the agency held comparative hearings (beauty
contests) to decide which party would best serve the public
interest and thereby receive the FCCs free renewable license.
This process collapsed of its own
weight in the early 1980s as the FCC prepared to assign the first
set of licenses for cellular telephone service. The agency was swamped
with applicants and appealed to Congress to allow other allocation
methods. Congress responded by authorizing lotteries for the free
licenses.
The lotteries were duly conducted.
But the FCC and Congress soon realized that the process was arbitrary
and that many lottery winners simply flipped their licenses
and earned large windfall profits. Accordingly, the FCC and Congress
considered other alternatives. Auctions seemed a natural choice. But
incumbent license holders especially broadcasters feared
that auctions for new spectrum allocations might someday be the precedent
for auctioning their (currently free) spectrum parcels and fiercely
opposed them.
evertheless,
Congress, desperate to raise budgetary revenue, authorized auctions
in 1993. As of June 2001, 34 auctions, many of them for cell phone
spectrum usage, had raised about $42 billion. Despite some glitches,
the auctions have been a substantial success. Cell phone usage has
exploded; over a third of total U.S. telephone lines today
are cell phones. But while they were a welcome improvement, the auctions
have affected only a small fraction of the usable spectrum. Use and
service restrictions still apply even for the slivers of spectrum
that have been auctioned. In the end, auctions have been simply another
assignment method occurring within the larger FCC allocation process.
An Unworkable System
This allocation system simply cant
be efficient, or even equitable. At its foundation, the FCCs
spectrum management process rests upon a fallacy: that the agency
knows exactly the right uses of the right bands of spectrum in the
right places using the right technologies and by the right parties
in every instance. As new technologies arise, Congress expects
the FCC will recognize them and unerringly accommodate them.
quick
comparison easily shows the absurdity of these expectations. Imagine,
for a moment, that private ownership of real estate was not permitted
in the United States and that a single federal agency made all decisions
as to the specific uses to which specific land parcels could be put,
the technologies that could be used on them, and who would be allowed
to use the land rent-free, with indefinitely renewable leases.
|

"Only by propertyzing the
spectrum i.e. applying real-estate-like property rights
to the spectrum will we unleash the full potential
of this immensely valuable but invisible national resource."
|
If the FCC were perfect and omniscient,
and if incumbents didn't lobby fiercely to retain their spectrum parcels
once granted, the system might work as designed. But all too often
the FCC has discouraged competition, and favored incumbents over entrants
and innovators all the while claiming its decisions and actions
were in the public interest. In the early 1950s, in the
name of encouraging a local orientation for television channels, the
FCC assigned channels in a way that made nearly impossible the formation
of more national networks beyond the three incumbents. In the 1960s
and 1970s, the FCC impeded the expansion of cable television. In the
1980s and 1990s the FCC and the Congress stymied the expansion of
locally based (wireless cable) and satellite-based (direct
broadcast satellite) alternatives to incumbent local cable companies.
The FCC delayed the initial rollout of cellular telephone service
by 10-15 years, and then initially licensed only two carriers per
region in such a way as to reduce the competitive pressures that cellular
telephone would bring. And the FCC's national allocation patterns
of spectrum for mobile radio uses have meant, for example, that forestry
communications allocations have lain idle in New York City, while
its allocations of spectrum for taxicab communications have been idle
in Idaho.
There are other drawbacks. The FCCs
management process, combined with the free licenses, has yielded shortages
of spectrum for current uses. And the spectrum shortage
has provided a justification (unfortunately, upheld by the Supreme
Court) for the FCC and the Congress to impose content obligations
on radio and television broadcasters that would be outrageous Constitutional
violations if applied to the print media.
The problem is not clumsiness or
incompetence by FCC personnel. The FCC has been, is, and will continue
to be staffed by knowledgeable, able, hard-working individuals, with
capable leadership. But its task is impossible. No organization could
gather all the necessary information, process it, and make the right
decisions and then do so again and again, as technology and/or
economic conditions change. And a cautious, bureaucratic environment
with constant, frequently excruciating pressures from Congress and
lobbyists is not one that encourages innovation and entrepreneurship.
A Better Way
There is a better way and U.S. real
estate provides a good model.
At first blush, the two spheres dont
seem to have much in common. But upon examination, real estate and
spectrum share a great deal of similarities, and their management
and use present some of the same challenges. Both are finite. Productive
land is scarce; the same is true of spectrum. As with
land, different types of spectrum are often inherently better suited
for different uses. Technological change can improve the efficiency
of the use of both land and spectrum. Technological change can expand
the amount of land that is considered usable and productive; ditto
for spectrum. And some uses of both land and spectrum may interfere
with neighboring uses of the same resource.
The solution is thus to construct
a legal and regulatory regime that would treat spectrum much the way
our legal system currently treats real estate. Heres how, in
principle, it would work:
The government would recognize a
property right (in perpetuity) for an owner to transmit over a specified
spectrum band, so long as the signals do not exceed a specified strength
beyond specified geographic boundaries during a specified time period.
The owners of such parcels would have the right to be free from others'
transmissions that interfered with the reception of their own spectrum
transmission. Owners, including government agencies, would be free
to sub-divide and to buy and sell parcels. Owners would also have
the right not to use their parcels, just as real estate owners do.
Non-use would make sense if, for example, spectrum use requires investment
in complementary facilities and the owner expects that technological
change or uncertainty could render current investments obsolete. The
antitrust laws would, of course, apply. And interference claims would
initially be addressed through negotiations, with ultimate recourse
to the courts.

"The solution is thus to construct
a legal and regulatory regime that would treat spectrum
much the way our legal system currently treats real
estate."
|
|
|
An interim expert agency
would initially configure the entire set of spectrum parcels,
which would then be auctioned. Winning bidders could subsequently
buy and sell so as to reconfigure their parcels and renegotiate beyond-boundary
signal-strength limits among themselves. As new technologies open
new possibilities and as economic demands for spectrum-use change,
the owners of parcels would be free continually to reconfigure the
parameters of their parcels. Formal or informal spectrum markets,
with brokers and other intermediaries, would surely develop rapidly
to help owners buy, sell, lease, or rent parcels.
This would not be privatization;
it would be propertyzing. Under the new regime, government
agencies could bid for and become owners of spectrum, just as they
currently hold and own real estate and other forms of property. Current
government/public uses of spectrum public radio and TV broadcasting,
defense and public safety communications, emergency communications
channels, radio astronomy, etc. could continue, so long as
taxpayers are willing to fund the purchase and maintenance of the
spectrum facilities. To facilitate transactions and assist in the
enforcement of property rights, a national registry of spectrum ownership
would be maintained, comparable to local land registries.
How to Get There from Here
Imposing this ideal structure on
the current spectrum system would be politically impossible. There
are tens of thousands of incumbent holders of FCC-issued licenses,
and virtually all of them treat their licenses as de facto property.
Many bought their licenses indirectly by purchasing companies that
already owned licenses. Tens of billions of dollars of investments
in facilities, equipment, personnel, and brand-name reputation surround
those licenses.
ut
we can start from where we are today. The FCCs licenses constitute
a set of de facto properties, with protections against interference.
Unfortunately, the licenses are often defined in terms of inputs (the
power of a transmitter, the height of the transmitting tower) rather
than in the output terms of a signals strength beyond a territory
perimeter. Nevertheless, these licenses should simply be assigned,
as is, to their incumbent holders in perpetuity, with the existing
protections against interference. This would appear to be a giveaway
of valuable public properties. But the FCC has already given away
most of the usable spectrum through its licenses, with their near-automatic
renewals. And it is unrealistic to believe that incumbent holders
of these licenses would readily yield them back to the Federal Government
at zero cost. (Because the new flexibility in use could be a windfall
for incumbents, the possibility of taxing some of the windfall gains
ought to be considered.)
The owners of these licenses could
then sub-divide, buy, sell, lease, or rent their parcels. Further,
they could begin to adjust their input combinations, so long as they
did not violate the interference restrictions that are implicit in
the license, or they could negotiate mutually advantageous arrangements
with transmission neighbors. Interference disputes that
could not be settled by negotiation would, during an initial transition
period, be referred to the FCC for arbitration. The FCC should hasten
this process by offering (quickly) to redefine the input-oriented
licenses into roughly equivalent output-oriented licenses. After the
transition period, disputes would be referred to the courts rather
than to the FCC, and the FCC would transform itself into a restricted-scope
pollution (interference) control agency, with economic
efficiency as its goal.
Bands of spectrum that are currently
under-utilized should be auctioned.
Government agencies would receive
the same property rights to their currently held spectrum licenses
as would other holders; but Congress should require government agencies
to make a special evaluation of their spectrum inventories and to
auction the surplus. The government currently holds a claim on about
a third of the usable spectrum, which is substantially in excess of
what it needs. In the late 20th century, Congress successfully legislated
disposals of surplus military real estate (military bases); it could
do the same with surplus spectrum. The market prices for spectrum
that will quickly emerge will provide a valuable benchmark for the
Congress and spur disposal decisions.
Benefits of Propertyzing
There are many benefits to this approach.
In a property rights regime, the owners of spectrum could flexibly
adapt their uses for broadcasting, telephone, data transmission,
Internet, mobile radio, and any new uses that might arise to
new technologies and new economic demands. A spectrum drought
would be impossible; artificial scarcities could not exist. The scarcity
justification for the First Amendment restrictions on broadcasting
would vanish.
f
course, a system of property rights and markets for spectrum use would
sometimes reach outcomes that, with the benefit of 20/20 hindsight,
arent the most efficient. Entrepreneurs make mistakes; markets
are not perfect. But a system of property rights and markets for spectrum
would be far less likely to be biased toward incumbency and discouraging
innovation, as the FCC has been. In the fast-changing world of the
21st century, a propertyzed spectrums flexibility
and responsiveness would surely bring high returns to the U.S. economy.
With the FCC (and Congress) removed
from the processes of spectrum allocation and assignment, radio and
television over-the-air broadcasting, cable transmission, local microwave
(wireless cable) transmission, and satellite-based transmission would
be unleashed to compete. Similarly, cellular telephone and other mobile
communication services would be freed from regulatory shackles; an
even greater cornucopia of competitive innovations would surely follow.
A Brave New World
Some might object that this scheme
would lead the FCC to abandon its charge to maintain the public
interest. But the public interest is a vague, ill-defined
concept, which has led the government to establish far too many anti-competitive,
anti-innovative, inflexible, output-limiting, anti-First Amendment
regulatory regimes.
Others might argue that the property
rights regime might favor large and powerful corporations over individual
entrepreneurs. But most holders of current FCC licenses including
large corporations such as General Electric (NBC), Viacom (CBS), Disney
(ABC), Verizon, and AT&T are not exactly the meek and the
poor. The FCC stewardship and licensing system has in fact imposed
severe limitations on general access to spectrum use, and the limitations
have favored rich individuals and sizable companies. Though spectrum
ownership would surely mimic the distribution found for other kinds
of property richer individuals would own more a property
rights system would democratize this valuable resource. Antitrust
laws would apply to spectrum markets, just as they apply to most other
markets in the U.S.
The transformation is not likely
to be friction-free or uncontroversial. Though aggressive actions
by a propertyzing minded FCC could surely move spectrum
policy strongly in the right directions, ultimately the Congress would
have to pass new laws.
But under a property rights system
the spectrum truly would approach real estate in its rights and uses.
And the U.S. economy would be all the better for it.
Lawrence J. White is the Arthur
E. Imperatore professor of economics at NYU Stern.