
By Sally Blount-Lyon
CONTRARY
TO POPULAR BELIEF,
FREE MARKETS NEVER WERE FAIR
ntil
recently, most business people possessed a bedrock of faith in the
efficiency, power, and fairness of markets. And a great deal of it
was justified. When trade occurs freely, the maximum amount of wealth
is created for the largest number of people. There is no more effective
social system for organizing people and allocating resources than
markets. But while markets are efficient, there’s nothing inherently
fair about them.
Yet, many smart people have fallen prey
to this belief. For the past two years, John Jost of Stanford University
and I have conducted research on peoples’ attitudes toward markets.
Our conclusion: many intelligent people are prone to the “fair
market illusion.” That is, they have tended to believe –
incorrectly – that market outcomes are inherently fair and that
the market process of determining how resources are allocated is a
fair one.
What Is Fairness?
Of course, the concept of fairness is
quite complex. Psychologically, the idea emanates from social comparison
processes – our tendency to compare ourselves with our people
– and the need for control and predictability in life. As psychologist
Melvin Lerner demonstrated in the 1960s, people have a need to believe
that life is controllable, and that life’s outcomes are fair.
But life isn’t “fair.” People’s life circumstances
are quite diverse and subject to chance events. Thus considered, any
sense that fairness exists at all is an illusion – albeit a
widespread one!
As a consequence, social psychologists
have spent a considerable amount of energy over the last 20 years
trying better to understand the nature of our fairness illusions.
In the process, psychologists have identified three types of fairness
judgments that people tend make: outcome, procedural, and process.
Regarding outcomes, fairness can be
thought of as a judgment that people make regarding the acceptable
degree of equality (or inequality) across parties’ payoffs in
particular situations. As an example, people often think of even splits
as fair. Psychologist Morton Deutsch has identified three types of
outcome fairness that people tend to make: based on equality, equity
(in proportion to earned rights or inputs), and need (given first
to those in need). As he found, equality norms are most prevalent
in friendships – i.e., we generally split restaurant bills evenly.
Equity norms, by contrast, are more common in business relationships.
People generally find it fair that those who invest more receive a
greater share of returns.
Fairness judgments are also often made
regarding the procedures used to generate outcomes, particularly when
it may not be possible to achieve outcome fairness. Procedural fairness
norms help organize expectations about how scarce resources will be
distributed across many people. For example, people often perceive
that flipping a coin is a fair way to determine between two people
who will get a one-of-a-kind item. Lotteries, first-come-first-served
lines, and rationing are also commonly accepted fair procedures. Psychologist
Gerald Leventhal has identified several characteristics commonly associated
with fair procedures. These include consistency across people, being
based on accurate information, correctable in the case of error, structured
to suppress bias, and reflecting prevailing ethical norms.
People also apply fairness judgments
to evaluate how social interactions unfold – i.e. the process.
In social interactions, people like to feel respected and that their
needs have been given adequate consideration. When this does not happen,
people say that they were unfairly treated.
Applying Fairness to Markets
Understanding fairness perceptions in
markets is especially challenging, because some aspects of markets
appear “fair,” and others do not. For example, one of
the fair aspects of markets is that they allow everyone equal access.
Theoretically, anyone can participate, regardless of gender, race,
or background. On the other hand, because the way people participate
in markets is through economic currency, markets seem to have an unfair
income bias. Because buyers who have more money can afford to pay
more for goods, they tend to get more in a market system. It is this
income bias that motivates governments to prohibit certain goods,
such as donor organs, from being allocated through markets.
"Psychologically,
the idea [of fairness] emanates from social comparison processes
– our tendency to compare ourselves with other people
– and the need for control and predictability in life." |
Sometimes, instead of saying that markets
are fair, people use the term “fair market price.” Here,
market price typically refers to available information about what
other people have recently paid for a similar good or service, or
the price at which other sellers are offering a similar item. In thick
markets – such as soda or personal computers – prices
vary little, and it is relatively easy to identify what is perceived
as a prevailing market price. In thin markets, where pricing is more
variable, such as fine art or nuclear fuel, identifying a prevailing
market price is more difficult.
Many people characterize a prevailing
market price as the “fair market price.” While that price
may intuitively “feel” good, there is nothing particularly
fair about it. Yes, it does represent a market clearing price –
that is, a price at which many buyers and sellers are willing to exchange.
But there is nothing inherently just about that point. In theoretical
terms, it simply represents a point in two-dimensional, price-quality
space where the two abstract lines (supply and demand) cross. While
that point is efficient, no economist worth his or her degree would
ever claim that that point is intrinsically fair. Consider, for example,
an unregulated monopoly. There may be a well-defined market price,
but the seller typically garners most of the surplus. Is that fair?
Probably not, and that’s why governments often seek to regulate
monopolies.
Besides, supply and demand curves don’t
explicitly exist in real life. No one ever gets all of the buyers
and all of the sellers in a market together at the same time to ask
them (a) how many units they each want to buy or sell, and (b) what
the maximum (or minimum) price is that they are willing to accept.
Further, no one then takes that information and aligns all of these
prices in descending order (for buyers) and ascending order (for sellers)
to see where these two plots intersect. The supply-demand framework
is a theoretical model that captures some important nuances about
markets – but it is not what real life looks like. And by and
large, it is not how markets actually work.
In the end, our research suggests that,
to the extent that fairness is assumed in markets, it has more to
do with procedural fairness than with outcome or process fairness.
Transacting at the prevailing market price feels good, because you
feel you are being treated in a just manner. Enacting a market price-based
transaction implies a procedure that is consistent across bargainers,
free of bias, based on data that is representative and relevant, and
is culturally appropriate.
Biased Judgements?
Interestingly, there is substantial
research that finds that the degree to which people associate market
outcomes with fairness may be subject to cognitive biases and contextual
framing. For example, it has been found that people typically perceive
that market outcomes are more fair when they result in wage increases
than wage decreases. In addition, market outcomes are considered more
fair when they lead to sudden decreases in buying prices rather than
sudden increases. In addition, there is a status quo bias at work.
Situations that don’t change feel more fair than situations
that do. Prices that do not change, or change only slightly, are usually
perceived as most fair.
Research also finds that people tend
to favor the fairness norms that favor their own interests. In market
contexts, this tendency has at least two implications. First, when
market outcomes favor one party over another, the party who benefits
is more likely to use the “markets-are-fair” rationalization
to justify the outcome. The more advantaged party is more likely to
rationalize his comparative win, because “everyone agrees that
markets are fair.” Second, this tendency means that in thin
market contexts – those in which pricing is perceived to vary
– people tend to selectively anchor on “comparables”
that favor their own position and believe in the inherent fairness
of that information as a reasonable reference point for resolving
the situation.
In a clever paper studying teacher contract
negotiations, Linda Babcock and her colleagues at Carnegie Mellon
University presented data that vividly demonstrates this bias. Specifically,
they found that mean teacher salaries in school districts that unions
view as being comparable to their own tend to be significantly higher
than mean teacher salaries in districts that school boards view as
being comparable to their own. Babcock and colleagues also found that
strike activity is positively correlated with the size of the difference
between the comparables that a union and school board bring to the
table.

"Procedural fairness norms
help organize expectations about how scarce resources will be
distributed across many people. For example, people often perceive
that flipping a coin is a fair way to determine between two
people who will get a one-of-a-kind item." |
Research that I have conducted with
Margaret Neale of Stanford University and Melissa Thomas-Hunt of Cornell
University shows that in thick market contexts, the fair market illusion
often leads people to overweight the validity of market-based data.
We told negotiators in our research laboratory that they were negotiating
the hypothetical sale of either an antique carousel horse or a new
stereo. We told them how much they could afford to spend, and what
they thought the item was worth. They were also given common information
about the price at which a single, similar transaction had recently
closed. When negotiating for the antique, the bargainers were much
less influenced by the single piece of market data than when they
were when negotiating for the stereo. People assumed that stereos
are more commodity-like, and bargainers in both roles mistakenly used
the market data as a proxy for market price. They assumed that it
was the “right” and “fair” way to resolve
the negotiation – even though it represented only one other
recent trade. In the stereo context, both buyers and sellers fell
prey to the fair market illusion to a degree that overweighted the
available market data in setting price.
To examine the fair market illusion
more deeply, my colleague John Jost and I have been collecting survey
data from undergraduate students, MBA students, and executives at
Stanford University, the University of Chicago, and New York University
for the last two years. And we have found the “fair market illusion”
to be rampant among people well-educated in economics. For example,
the average MBA student is likely to agree just as strongly with the
statement, “The free market system is a fair system,”
as with the statement, “The free market system is an efficient
system.” Training in economic courses does not seem to improve
the correctness of these answers between the first and second years.
We did, however, find that within these
populations, some people are more prone to the belief than are others.
For example, we have found that the degree to which people fall prey
to the fair market illusion is strongly correlated with the degree
to which people report being politically conservative rather than
liberal. It is also strongly correlated with espoused beliefs that
hierarchies are natural and social inequality is inevitable.
Together all these findings have two
important implications. First, they suggest that many people trained
in business schools are leaving with an incorrect understanding of
what markets are and what markets aren’t. Markets are about
creating wealth and allocating resources efficiently – not necessarily
intelligently or compassionately. Markets are not intrinsically just,
intelligent, or moral. Free trade can not by itself make sure that
the poor get fed, the best ideas receive funding, and the world becomes
a qualitatively better place.
Further, when people believe that markets
are fair, they are prone to systematic processing errors and bandwagon
effects. The fair market illusion leads people to overweight readily
available market data when making financial decisions and become overconfident
of their decisions. This tendency lends some insight into the inflated
stock market valuations from two years ago. While many stocks were
trading at particularly high prices, those prices were clearly not
sensible or intelligent, and certainly not “fair.”
Sally Blount-Lyon is professor of
management at NYU Stern.