

The Rise and Uncertain Future
of Mezzanine Financing and Land Banking
Through the use of techniques
like mezzanine financing and land banks, developers of large
residential real estate projects have been able to borrow and
still keep debt off their balance sheets. Now that investors
are eyeing off-balance sheet debt with a greater level of suspicion,
will these tactics continue to rise?
By Jeanne Calderon |
Real estate development is the art of
using other people’s money. From Donald Trump to small-town
builders, developers typically strive to use as much borrowed cash
and as little of their own funds as possible. Doing so lets them diversify
holdings and minimize exposure to the risk of loss, particularly if
the lender does not require personal guarantees. In recent years,
this desire has lead to the development of creative financing techniques
in large-scale residential development. Trends such as mezzanine financing
and land banking enable developers to shift land-acquisition and development
debt off their balance sheets. In the wake of the Enron debacle, as
investors and regulators begin to clamp down on off-balance-sheet
financing, these controversial methods are receiving more scrutiny.
In traditional real estate financings,
borrowers give a mortgage on their property to lenders in exchange
for funding. Although many real estate loan transactions involve only
one mortgage – the “first mortgage” or “senior
mortgage” – borrowers frequently obtain additional financing
through a second mortgage, often referred to as the “junior
mortgage.” To prevent borrowers from becoming over-leveraged,
lenders typically use a loan-to-value ratio, under which the first
mortgage holder limits its loan to a certain percentage of the property’s
appraised value. The junior mortgage holder may then lend an additional
amount, usually at a higher interest rate. The first mortgage holder
has the more secure rights of recovery in a foreclosure or bankruptcy
action.
The bank typically funds between 70
percent and 85 percent of the purchase price for the acquisition of
land. To ensure that developers have a significant financial commitment
to the project, many banks now require developers to fund a substantially
greater portion of the acquisition from their own funds. The same
bank generally also commits to funding the development – i.e.
the seeking and obtaining of governmental approvals and building of
infrastructure such as roads and sewers – and the construction
of the homes. The lender also may require the developer’s principals
to guaranty the developer’s obligations to the lender, including
the repayment of the debt. In this instance, the lender is a secured
creditor – i.e. the borrower’s obligations are secured
by a mortgage on the property.
The presence of junior, or second mortgages,
can be a complicating factor – especially when deals turn sour.
Junior mortgage holders often have the financial ability to obstruct
a first mortgage foreclosure, even when borrowers can’t. Meanwhile,
the default of a second mortgage and the commencement of a foreclosure
action by its holder can create problems for senior mortgage lenders.
In addition, in transactions involving the securitization of a portfolio
of senior mortgage loans, rating agencies have been particularly concerned
about the bankruptcy risks posed by junior mortgages.
As a result, since the early 1990s,
the use of junior mortgages has decreased. At the same time, however,
developers’ need and desire to borrow more funds than mortgage
lenders are willing to lend them has continued to rise. And that has
helped create a market for so-called mezzanine loans.
Next Stop: The Mezzanine
Mezzanine loans provide non-mortgage
subordinate financing to developers, without subjecting first mortgage
lenders to all the negative aspects of subordinate mortgage financing.
Mezzanine loans, which can be made by investment banks, stock funds,
banks, and insurance companies, typically supply financing of between
50 percent and 90 percent of the project’s required equity contributions
or capital structure cost. Unlike plain vanilla mortgages, mezzanine
financings take a variety of forms, including hybrid financial products
with equity characteristics, such as a participating return and equity
kickers. In the case of equity kickers, the lender’s stated
return may be supplemented based on the performance of the borrower
or the project.
There’s another crucial difference:
mezzanine lenders generally don’t lend to the corporate or legal
entity that has taken out the mortgage on the land. Rather, they extend
credit to the partners, members, or other equity owners of the borrower
– as individuals or as a group – and take a pledge of
their equity interests in the borrower. Less frequently, the mezzanine
lender may take a preferred equity position in the borrower directly.
This interest entitles the lender to distributions of excess cash
flow after debt service, ahead of any distributions or other payments
to the borrower’s principals. Yet another approach combines
a senior mortgage with mezzanine financing at a combined loan-to-value
ratio of 90 percent to 95 percent – at a rate that may be blended
or kept separate. In this case, the senior lender and mezzanine lender
are the same entity. This last type of structure may contain a shared
appreciation or equity kicker, an exit fee paid by the borrower, or
both.
In any of the above structures, it is
common for the lender to require personal guarantees from the mezzanine
borrower. After all, the borrower’s obligation to repay the
debt is not secured by the real estate. Consequently, the mezzanine
lender’s interest is exposed to greater risk than a second mortgage
lender in a conventional mortgage situation. To compensate the lender
for such risk, the “blended” interest rate paid by the
senior and mezzanine borrowers is greater than the rate paid to a
secured mortgage lender. And while senior mortgage debt is generally
at a fixed rate, the interest rate on a mezzanine loan may fluctuate.
Also, the mezzanine lender may insist on a certain level of control
over the borrower’s business as a means to protect its investment.
But that level of control must be limited to avoid subjecting the
lender to fiduciary responsibility and other liabilities.
The first and most critical hurdle to
overcome in mezzanine financing is whether the senior lender will
permit it and, if so, under what terms and conditions. As in conventional
financing, typically the senior lender will require the borrower to
provide equity from her own funds or assets, rather than by means
of further indebtedness. This hurdle pivots, in part, on whether the
mezzanine financing is viewed as debt or equity. If the mezzanine
financing is viewed as debt, then this is added to the debt to be
advanced by the senior lender in calculating the loan-to-value ratio.
But if the mezzanine financing is viewed as equity, the amount is
counted towards the equity furnished by the borrower. The conclusion
depends on the viewpoint of the lender as well as the form that the
mezzanine financing takes. In addition, the senior and mezzanine lenders
enter into an intercreditor agreement to address their respective
rights.
On the developer’s balance sheet,
the senior loan is reflected as a liability and the land is reflected
as an asset. But a mezzanine loan appears as a liability on the balance
sheet of the borrower – not the developer. As a result, the
mezzanine debt does not adversely affect the developer’s net
worth and liquidity. The interest expense allocable to the senior
loan is treated as an interest expense on the developer’s statement
and the mezzanine loan interest is treated as an interest expense
on the statement of the mezzanine borrower. Both types of lenders
recognize the corresponding amounts as interest income.
The interest of the senior lender is
similar to that of the senior lender in a conventional real estate
financing. But because the mezzanine lender is not a lender with respect
to the entity that owns the property, it has no interest in the property.
Instead, the lender’s interest varies depending upon the type
of mezzanine structure. For example, the mezzanine lender may have
a security interest in the shares of stock, partnership interest,
or other equity interest in the entity that owns the property.
A major concern of all mezzanine lenders
is the potential ability of the senior borrower to declare bankruptcy.
The senior lender has a high priority as a secured creditor of the
bankruptcy estate, whereas the mezzanine lender has no security interest
in the borrower. Furthermore, the borrowers under the mezzanine loan
may have guarantees or other obligations that are triggered by the
bankruptcy of the senior borrower.
In an effort to deal with this risk,
the senior borrower frequently appoints an “independent”
director to its board. This independent director exists for one purpose
only: to vote against allowing the senior borrower from filing for
a reorganization in bankruptcy. An issue arises where the mezzanine
lender seeks to appoint a director who is not truly independent –
i.e. who may have some relationship to the mezzanine lender. In that
case, the director’s vote may be challenged under the “interested
director” provisions of state corporate law, with the result
that the vote will not be taken into account.
Other techniques to control key decisions
of the senior borrower include the creation of a special class of
shareholders whose vote is required on major issues, or a pledge of
shares to the mezzanine lender to allow it to take over the senior
borrower in certain instances. Mezzanine lenders holding “kicker”
or similar interests also focus on having rights to control any action
by the borrowers that may adversely affect the value of those residual
or participatory interests. Within the loan documents, some lenders
seek detailed veto and control rights that amount to participation
in routine business matters.
Debt or Equity?
Whether the mezzanine financing is viewed
as “debt” or “equity” has a profound impact
on a variety of issues. Senior lenders, as well as borrowers, find
useful legal ambiguity in these elements of mezzanine loans. The equity
characteristics – such as kickers – expose the mezzanine
lender to challenges from the senior lender and the mezzanine borrower.
They may argue that the mezzanine lender is in fact equitably subordinated
to competing lenders, or is not in fact a lender. This may create
defenses to foreclosure and may also limit the mezzanine lender’s
rights if a bankruptcy petition does succeed. Challenges based on
the claim that the mezzanine debt is in fact equity, or that the mezzanine
lender is an insider of the borrower by virtue of the appointment
of the independent director and other controls discussed above, are
starting to surface. Thus, the techniques used to control bankruptcy
risk may in fact increase the risk of loss to the mezzanine lender
in an eventual enforcement action.
It has become increasingly common for
mezzanine lenders to require that the principals of the senior borrower
form a new entity to act as the mezzanine borrower. This mezzanine
borrower entity generally is structured as a so-called “bankruptcy
remote entity,” that is separate from the borrowing entity that
obtains the first mortgage loan. The bankruptcy of the senior borrower
will thus not have any impact on the separate structure of the mezzanine
borrower.
Pay As You Go
In recent years, developers and lenders
have created a new means of funding development: land banks. In a
land bank transaction, a developer locates a parcel of undeveloped
real estate that it wishes ultimately to acquire in its developed
state. In contrast to mortgage financing, in which large sums are
borrowed up-front, land banks offer developers a sort of pay-as-you
go process. The land bank, which is typically an investment bank or
other financier unrelated to the developer, acquires the property.
(As regulated entities, commercial banks generally are prohibited
from engaging in such transactions.) At the same time, the developer
enters into an agreement to acquire the building lots from the land
banker, on a periodic basis, after the lots are improved. Land banks
are most prevalent in areas such as the Sunbelt.
The land banker funds the costs associated
with the development of the project’s infrastructure. Sometimes,
the land banker retains the developer to shepherd the land through
the government approval process and to construct the infrastructure.
Typically the developer is paid a guaranteed maximum price plus a
fee. The developer then buys the improved lots from the land banker,
and often obtains financing for the purchase of the improved lots
from a conventional lender. The purchase price is a fixed amount per
lot, frequently based on a predetermined formula designed to result
in the land banker achieving a certain internal rate of return on
its total investment.
Under this structure, the developer’s
acquisition of the property is deferred until after the property is
developed and improved. And since the developer typically has the
option (rather than the obligation) to purchase the lots, the developer
is subject to less risk than in a conventional mortgage or mezzanine
financing. The developer does not make any payments until and unless
she purchases the lots. And if the developer decides not to purchase,
typically she merely forfeits the deposit or down payment. One of
the reasons that land bank contracts typically do not provide for
their specific performance in the event of a developer’s default
is that the developer would face a greater risk that the transaction
will not be viewed as a sale, and thus would be required to reflect
the obligation to purchase the lots on its balance sheet.
Developers pay a price for such flexibility,
however. Land bank transactions typically result in higher costs to
the developer than does mezzanine financing. And due to the risks
involved and the limited number of land bankers in the market, the
use of land banks is typically reserved for those instances where
the developer is able to locate for purchase property which is priced
under the market. Often times the property involved is distressed
property sold at a dramatic discount.
Costs and Benefits
Compared with mortgages and mezzanine
loans, the land bank structure results in the greatest leveraging
of the land purchase price by the developer. The only cash payment
by the developer at the outset of the transaction is the down payment
or deposit. Periodic interest payments are not due during the development
process. As the developer purchases and closes on lots, the purchase
price includes a portion allocable to the land purchase price and
the balance allocable to the built-in “interest.” Although
the built-in “interest” in a land bank results in a higher
price for the lots, the developer has less risk because she defers
the payment until she is more likely to need the land for construction
of a home for resale. The built-in “interest” rate tends
to be significantly higher than in the conventional mortgage situation,
but is in a similar range to the rate charged by mezzanine lenders.
When it comes to balance sheets, the
developer does not reflect the land as an asset because it merely
has the contractual right to purchase it. Once the developer takes
down a lot, the land is reflected as an asset. And the mortgage financing
that the developer obtained for acquisition and construction of the
individual lots becomes a liability. The developer’s income
statement does not reflect as an interest expense the portion of the
land purchase price that is the profit element portion of the purchase
price payable to the land banker.
Keeping the land and a corresponding
liability off its books during the acquisition and development process
is a tremendous benefit to the developer. It enhances the developer’s
ability to obtain financing for its operations, and loan-to-value
ratio remains stronger than it would be even compared to the mezzanine
loan structure. This arrangement is particularly useful for public
developers, as their earnings per share are not diluted when the land
is not producing income. At least one publicly traded builder, Lennar
Corp., has established an affiliate that acquires the land and owns
it through the development process until the public builder is ready
to use the land for construction and resale to its customers.
There are pitfalls to this approach.
The land bank must be carefully structured to ensure that the deal
is treated as a sale between the land banker and developer, and not
re-characterized as a loan. If that happens, the developer loses the
benefits of “off balance sheet” financing because it would
have to reflect a large liability on the balance sheet.
If properly structured, the land banker
should be respected as the owner of the property for income tax purposes,
until the closing on the sale of the relevant portions of the property
to the developer. As such, the land banker recognizes ordinary income
from the sale of the lots as the closings on the lots occur. No portion
of the purchase price is allocable to interest, with respect to either
the land banker or the developer.
However, there may be a risk that the
Internal Revenue Service will attack the land bank as merely a financing
device rather than a true “sale.” Although there are no
cases, regulations or other interpretations on point, in other contexts,
the courts have upheld the IRS’s position that a transaction
structured as a sale should be re-characterized to reflect the underlying
nature of the transaction.
If the developer defaults on its obligation
to purchase all or a portion of the property from the land banker,
the developer might seek to file for bankruptcy protection. When doing
so, it might assert that the transaction was merely a financing device
and request that the court treat the property as an asset of the bankruptcy
estate of the developer. If the court were to grant relief to the
developer, an interesting issue would be whether the court would treat
the land banker as a secured creditor – even though no mortgage
or security agreement exists. Perhaps, the court would recharacterize
the deed as a de facto mortgage. This is all speculative, since there
have been no reported decisions supporting this approach.
Quite apart from legal challenges, there
is a larger existential question surrounding the growth of mezzanine
loans, land banks, and other off-balance-sheet financing techniques.
Investors have suffered as a result of a series of episodes in which
it became apparent that publicly held companies were substantially
under-reporting their debt obligations. As a result, the entire financial
community is now shining a spotlight on innovative financing techniques.
And as investors and lenders demand simplicity and clarity in balance
sheets, borrowers may find that the benefits of off-balance sheet
financing may no longer outweigh its costs.
Jeanne A. Calderon is clinical associate
professor of business law at NYU Stern.